The prevention paradox or the inequality paradox?
نویسنده
چکیده
In February this year, a new edition of Geoffrey Rose’s classical book Strategy of Preventive Medicine was published, with a commentary by Kay-Tee Khaw and Michael Marmot. The commentary summarizes the life and work of Geoffrey Rose, explains the main content and impact of the classical book and gives plenty of examples that illustrate the validity of Rose’s theses. Coincidentally, in the February issue of the American Journal of Public Health, Frolich and Potvin published an article pointing out that interventions based on the population-based approach, advocated by Rose, may increase inequality in health. They give three examples on this and propose a strategy to mitigate such effects. The key messages of Geoffrey Rose may be summarized as follows: the distribution of risk levels for major determinants of disease follows a continuum in which the high-risk persons are at the extreme end. A large number of persons with moderately increased risk levels contribute more cases than a small number with extreme risk levels. Thus, interventions targeting the general population, aiming at shifting the risk curve to the left, are more effective than interventions targeting high-risk groups. This latter is called the prevention paradox, since it is not the individuals with moderately elevated risk that have the greatest benefit from such interventions. Frolich and Potvin, while acknowledging the important public health impact of Rose’s principles, mean that Rose did not address the underlying mechanisms that led to different distribution of risk in different social groups. They cite three examples in which interventions have increased health disparities, the most obvious one being information campaigns against smoking. They suggest that focus on vulnerable populations as target for public-health interventions should be a complement to the population-based approach. The concept ‘vulnerable groups’ denotes subgroups in society characterized by ‘shared social characteristics that put them at higher risk of risks’ and should thus be distinguished from high-risk groups according to the Rose risk distribution. Many public-health professionals and policy-makers have observed that public-health interventions often benefit to a higher extent those at lower risk, and thereby may increase inequality in health. Frolich and Potvin highlight an important phenomenon, and their modification of Rose’s risk curves, not shifting to the left, but rather extending over a larger area is illustrative. However, to state that Rose did not address inequality health, one must have missed the last pages of his book. The target for intervention advocated by Frolich and Potvin (table 2 of ref. 2) is to ‘shift to a lower level the risk exposure distribution of socially defined groups through changes in social and environmental conditions that make groups at higher risk of risks’. In fact, the wording by Rose is not very different in content (p. 160 of ref. 1): ‘socio-economic deprivation includes a whole constellation of closely interrelated factors such as lack of money, overcrowded and substandard housing . . . worse education, unsatisfying work or actual unemployment. . .’ and further on ‘Political changes which reduced economic inequalities would surely reduce also these health inequalities, with great benefit to national health overall’. The point is not to argue on ‘who was first’, since in that case, one might go to Virchow or other early proponents of a socio-economic perspective on public-health interventions. But a re-reading of Rose, together with the commentary by Khaw and Marmot, and the paper by Frolich and Potvin, helps us stimulate thinking about theoretical as well as empirical grounds for public-health intervention and their socio-economic consequences. It is easy to make the case that there can be no harm in adding a ‘vulnerable populations approach’ as a complement to the population approach. But Khaw and Marmot give an example in their commentary (p. 21 of ref. 1) showing that while interventions targeted to poorer groups might seem sensible, this is not without problems since i) one would have to set an arbitrary cut-off point for defining the vulnerable group and ii) the appropriate level of intervention may well be the whole of society. Are the population-based approach and the vulnerablepopulations approach complementary or contradictory? It depends, is probably the most appropriate answer. On circumstances, type of population, type of risk factor, etc. A clear policy implication is the need for careful monitoring and follow-up of public-health intervention, with focus on effects—intended or not—in different socioeconomic groups.
منابع مشابه
Bertrand’s Paradox Revisited: More Lessons about that Ambiguous Word, Random
The Bertrand paradox question is: “Consider a unit-radius circle for which the length of a side of an inscribed equilateral triangle equals 3 . Determine the probability that the length of a ‘random’ chord of a unit-radius circle has length greater than 3 .” Bertrand derived three different ‘correct’ answers, the correctness depending on interpretation of the word, random. Here we employ geomet...
متن کاملParadox in the Poetry of Hazin-e Lahiji
Paradox is one of the literary techniques in the poetry of the Safavid poets. Hazin-e Lahiji, like so many other poets of that age, employed this technique in his pursuit and showed that "unfamiliar meaning". Paradox is used in the poetry of Hazin-e Lahiji for the purpose of defamiliarization and exoticism. The poet in order to create new implications and subtle and insightful points and also t...
متن کاملHow Likely is Simpson's Paradox in Path Models?
Simpson’s paradox is a phenomenon arising from multivariate statistical analyses that often leads to paradoxical conclusions; in the field of e-collaboration as well as many other fields where multivariate methods are employed. We derive a general inequality for the occurrence of Simpson’s paradox in path models with or without latent variables. The inequality is then used to estimate the proba...
متن کاملThe Paradox of Health Policy: Revealing the True Colours of This ‘Chameleon Concept’; Comment on “The Politics and Analytics of Health Policy”
Health policy has been termed a ‘chameleon concept’, referring to its ability to take on different forms of disciplinarity as well as different roles and functions. This paper extends Paton’s analysis by exploring the paradox of health policy as a field of academic inquiry—sitting across many of the boundaries of social science but also marginalised by them. It situates contemporary approaches ...
متن کاملParadox and Relativism
Since the time of Plato, relativism has been attacked as a self-refuting theory. Today, there are two basic kinds of argument that are used to show that global relativism is logically incoherent: first, a direct descendent of the argument Plato uses against Protagoras, called the peritrope; and, second, a more recent argument that relativism leads to an infinite regress. Although some relativis...
متن کاملذخیره در منابع من
با ذخیره ی این منبع در منابع من، دسترسی به آن را برای استفاده های بعدی آسان تر کنید
برای دانلود متن کامل این مقاله و بیش از 32 میلیون مقاله دیگر ابتدا ثبت نام کنید
ثبت ناماگر عضو سایت هستید لطفا وارد حساب کاربری خود شوید
ورودعنوان ژورنال:
- European journal of public health
دوره 18 3 شماره
صفحات -
تاریخ انتشار 2008